GovWire

Speech: Merger control and public policy

Competition Markets Authority

October 2
11:54 2024

My family and friends do not always show a day-to-day interest in my decision-making role in the UKs merger control regime.

In 2021, I was not asked over Sunday lunch to explain the competition concerns I had about the merger of two suppliers of technology for pensions administration. Important though it was for the millions of people with pensions and other investments.

Nor, in 2022, did my mobile light-up when I chaired a group which cleared the London Stock Exchanges acquisition of Quantile a provider of portfolio compression and margin optimisation services.

A year may go by where merger control decisions are not of any great interest to anyone other than those directly affected by the deal and the specialist competition community, notwithstanding their importance for consumers and the wider economy.

2023 was not such a year. As chair of the inquiry group which prohibited Microsofts original deal to acquire Activision, I was aware of the considerable degree of interest from the media, the business community and even some of the general public. This year, it is the proposed merger between Vodafone and Three (in which I have no decision-making role) which is attracting attention.

Microsoft / Activision and Vodafone /Three sit alongside transactions such as Sainsburys / Asda, Kraft / Cadbury, Melrose / GKN and Pfizers attempted take-over of Astra Zeneca, as mergers triggering some degree of public debate.

While merger reviews generally may not be at the forefront of public awareness (one does not see merger control feature in opinion pollsters lists of major public concerns!) these cases, high profile or not, have an impact on issues that the public certainly do care about such as the cost-of-living and economic growth. That is where the CMA comes in our job, given to us by Parliament is to apply statutory tests, and use our skills and capabilities, to defend key economic interests.

Explaining the value of merger control

Given our important public functions and the significant powers we have to fulfil them, it is right that we are ready to explain our work, and the interests it serves. For some parts of the competition regime, the public impact of what we do needs little explanation. Most people understand that businesses meeting in secret to fix prices are as Adam Smith put it a conspiracy against the public. It is not hard to see that public wellbeing is served by vigorous enforcement.

Explaining how merger control contributes to the wider consumer good and economic prosperity is more complex. Partly, because M&A is a fairly standard business activity; it is widespread, usually transparent, and can produce a variety of benefits including a more efficient allocation of capital across the economy as a whole. So when we look at a merger, we are intervening in what would normally be considered an area of commercial autonomy.

A merger might affect investment, growth, resilience, national security, employment, regional development or how the UK is perceived internationally. Mergers can hold promise for, or raise concerns about, any one of these issues. And certainly, parties to a merger will make strong claims for the benefits it will bring.

Labours 2024 election manifesto stated that sustained economic growth is the only route to improving the prosperity of our country and the living standards of working people [Footnote 1]. Rachel Reeves, in her first speech as Chancellor, said that the new government would get Britains economy growing again and that there was no time to waste [Footnote 2]. It is therefore opportune to ask how competition policy, and in particular merger control, contributes to this growth mission.

For much of the last 45 years, competition policy was a core element of economic policy, with the belief that strong competition enforcement would support productivity, growth and innovation. While other policy instruments were employed to support specific sectors of the economy or places within the UK, these were considered to be complementary to competition policy.

Recent developments the pandemic, the Ukraine war, advances in technology, increasing focus on climate change, the cost-of-living crisis, and the rise of populist movements sceptical about the benefits of free trade have prompted debate about whether a more interventionist industrial strategy is needed to protect, shape and grow domestic markets. And, as I mentioned, the new government is committed to developing such a strategy. The UK is not alone in this commentators have observed what has been described as a global renaissance of industrial policy[Footnote 3]. Mario Draghis report on the future of European competitiveness is the most recent contribution to this debate [Footnote 4].

Many of the measures governments may consider under the banner of industrial policy such as skills and training, investment in infrastructure and support for research and development can be part of a coherent framework with competition policy. Competition authorities can contribute positively to the success of these policies by giving advice and, where necessary, undertaking investigations and enforcement activity to ensure the effective working of markets, as we did recently in our market studies on electric vehicle charging and housebuilding. Indeed, the UKs markets regime means that the CMA is exceptionally well equipped to support cross-government, mission led industrial policy; and we are seeing a lot of interest in our cutting-edge market investigation system from other countries keen to better connect competition policy to broader economic objectives.

The role of merger control in supporting national economic missions is perhaps more subtle but equally important. I propose, in the rest of this lecture, to discuss how merger control contributes to policies that support a growing, innovative and resilient economy and the impact of effective merger control on businesses in the UK. I shall consider whether we intervene too much and why we are interested in mergers between non-UK companies. Finally, I shall talk about how we are held to account for our activities.

But first, a caveat. As a competition specialist there is a risk that one sees the entire world through the prism of competition policy. We should not understate the significance of competition policy in driving economic growth, but other policies such as monetary and fiscal policy and trade are critical and there are sectors of the economy that may require more direct government support for markets to thrive. And there are aspects of our national life, such as health and education, which affect economic growth but where market forces will always be subsidiary to other important public goals.

That said, given the extensive academic and historical evidence, it is difficult to see how a productive, growing and innovative economy can be built and sustained without competition policy, including merger control, being an important element in the mix. This is one of the reasons we set up a Microeconomics Unit to conduct economic research focusing on issues of competition, innovation and productivity to support growth in the UK economy.

Why focus on competition?

In our day-to-day work, we apply the test that is enshrined in law whether a proposed merger may give rise to a substantial lessening of competition and what any reduction of competition might mean for consumers. We consider the potential impact of the merger on the prices consumers might pay, the quality of goods and services they may receive and how they might benefit from innovation.

Although the regime is centred around protecting the competitive process in markets impacted by specific transactions, it has a benefit for the UK economy that is broader, because competition is a major driver of productivity, growth and innovation in the economy as a whole.

The importance of competition for the economy was at the core of the reforms that established the modern merger control regime in 2002. The Blair government policy proposal that formed the basis of the legislation said: Vigorous competition between firms is the lifeblood of strong and effective markets. Competition helps consumers get a good deal. It encourages firms to innovate by reducing slack, putting downward pressure on costs and providing incentives for the efficient organisation of production. As such, competition is a central driver for productivity growth in the economy, and hence the UKs international competitiveness [Footnote 5].

So while we apply micro-economic analysis centred on a specific transaction, and what it might mean for competition in affected markets and relevant consumers, the system as a whole has important macro-economic consequences for all people in the UK, businesses and the wider economy.

This critical linkage between decisions on individual mergers and wider benefits to people, businesses and the economy is sometimes overlooked, so let me give an illustration. We recently carried out work in the groceries market as part of our efforts to support consumers and help contain cost-of-living pressures. While we identified some concerns, we found that high price inflation for groceries did not appear to have been driven at an aggregate level by weak competition between retailers. UK

Related Articles

Comments

  1. We don't have any comments for this article yet. Why not join in and start a discussion.

Write a Comment

Your name:
Your email:
Comments:

Post my comment

Recent Comments

Follow Us on Twitter

Share This


Enjoyed this? Why not share it with others if you've found it useful by using one of the tools below: